Skip to Main Content

This year has brought new treatments for osteoporosis, advanced bladder cancer, Ebola, tuberculosis, spinal muscular atrophy, and postpartum depression. And it’s only autumn — the season in which Congress and President Trump will decide to kill biomedical innovation with their proposals on drug prices just as we’re entering a new era of curative medicines.

The press is reporting on “bipartisan efforts to lower drug prices,” taking for granted that any debate about drug prices presumes that there are drugs to price.

advertisement

House Speaker Nancy Pelosi finally released her three-part plan to lower drug prices last week. The first two parts would be terrible for patients. The third is exactly what we need.

First bad idea: one price for the U.S., E.U., and Japan

Pelosi would peg U.S. drug prices to those paid by Japan and several European single-payer health care systems whose restrictive policies offer fewer innovative medicines to their citizens. This is similar to what President Trump has proposed before. But this well-intentioned price control would most likely push U.S. prices up, not down. Here’s why.

The pharmaceutical industry runs on profit margins of 10% to 20%, meaning there’s not much room to cut revenues before biotech becomes a giant nonprofit. The only logical response by companies would be to raise international prices to match those in the U.S., not to lower U.S. drug prices to match international ones. If other countries then cut back on their use of branded drugs, American companies will have to make up their losses by increasing prices.

advertisement

Pelosi’s plan blocks price increases on existing drugs. To remain profitable, companies would have to launch new drugs at even higher prices than they would have otherwise, anticipating they wouldn’t be able to sell them in Europe and Japan and therefore would need to generate all their returns from U.S. sales. So over the longer term, the U.S. would shoulder even more of the cost of innovation than it does now.

With her focus on what other countries pay, Pelosi appears to miss the point that it serves American patients for drug companies to get other countries to contribute at least something to the development of novel medicines. Yes, patients in those countries get medicines for less. But what American politicians should focus on is making sure that American patients have access to today’s treatments and the ones we have yet to invent.

If America won’t let other countries pay less and then, later on, when those countries stop paying for drugs, won’t agree to make up the difference by paying more, then the funding for new drug development will dry up and there won’t be any novel drugs to fuel our debates about price and affordability.

Second bad idea: outright price setting

The second part of Pelosi’s plan calls for government price controls on 250 drugs under Medicare. This means U.S. companies would not be allowed to set their own drug prices — even if they were the same as what other countries paid. The bill summary referred to these controls as a “negotiation” to bring down costs under Medicare, but its reach extends well beyond Medicare and doesn’t actually call for negotiation. Drug companies that do not acquiesce to pricing demands from the Department of Health and Human Services would face punitive taxes until they came to heel.

The massive expense of drug development is borne almost exclusively by private investors, and there are not many of them. Fundamentally, Pelosi seems to believe that the U.S. government should decide how much reward to mete out to successful innovators. The premise of her proposal is that “innovation does not benefit Americans if they cannot afford it.” But when only 1 in 25 drug candidates makes it from preclinical studies through to FDA approval, no one is going to put money on the 25-to-1 longshot if the house can announce after the race is over that the actual payout will be 5-to-1.

What Pelosi has proposed is worse than the central planning ideology already debunked by the collapse of the Soviet Union, which at least paid inventors’ salaries while they worked for the state. If she believes the myth that the government already funds drug development, I can see how it would sound fair that the state should set the price for its own intellectual property. This belief is shared by other elected representatives, including Sens. Bernie Sanders (I-Vt.) and Rick Scott (R-Fla.), who have been spreading tales that U.S. taxpayers substantially fund the development of new medicines. But this isn’t true.

The average National Institute of Health grant to a university researcher is under $1 million. Drug companies then risk an average of $1 to $2 billion to convert that basic research into a single FDA-approved drug.

Although most drugs are invented by industry, there’s no question that government-funded university research germinates some promising seeds that can sprout into lifesaving medicines. When it’s time to bring their discoveries from the lab to the clinic, universities seek to partner with companies and receive both guaranteed payments and royalties if those drugs succeed.

Drug companies pay workers, vendors, and manufacturers, and issue dividends to investors — all transactions taxed by Uncle Sam. No one is exploiting taxpayers here: Biopharma innovators commercialize new medicines for society while generating revenue for both the U.S. Treasury and research universities.

The math behind drug development is often twisted by pharma’s critics to suggest that there is widespread price gouging in the industry. But the drug industry’s profit margin fluctuates between 10% and 20%, less than that for the software and oil and gas industries. And after all of the rebates that are already negotiated by insurers — which should be passed onto patients but aren’t — there is little room for further cuts. Shaving even 20% off net drug prices would render the industry profitless and wipe out most executive compensation. While that might please some, a 20% discount wouldn’t make an immuno-oncology treatment affordable to a patient with poor insurance coverage.

Generics were once novel drugs

Prices are generally set at levels the market requires to keep the innovation engine churning out new drugs, which are only temporarily expensive before going generic, remaining useful yet inexpensive in perpetuity. As long as drugs keep going generic, the industry must keep inventing to stay afloat, which is good for patients. That drugs go generic when patents expire is the natural price control that’s always ensured that drugs offer great value in the long run.

Our growing mountain of generic drugs is a national treasure. Like a mortgage that is eventually paid off, what we pay for branded drugs — 1.3% of GDP — is a worthy investment, not an expense. Nothing else about health care goes generic: Surgery costs, for example are an ever-increasing rent. Drugs going generic without undue delay, as most do, is the price control we have long had and the only price control we need.

Pelosi’s price controls are just another way of saying that the government — which still continues to invest in sugar subsidies — would prefer to stop investing in new medicines. That means our children’s and grandchildren’s health care will be no better than our own. America is better than that.

Third time’s a charm: capping out-of-pocket costs

Our creative drive to cure diseases should be the pride and joy of America, not a scapegoat for a broken health insurance system. Patients currently shoulder $61 billion of out-of-pocket drug costs. Some are financially ruined by what they are asked to pay, and many more give up on treatment. Their plight fuels outrage in the media and inflammatory rhetoric, leading many to blame innovators for the hardships insurance companies impose on patients.

This is why I applaud the third part of Pelosi’s bill, which proposes much-needed insurance reforms to cap what patients pay out of pocket for the medicines they need. That’s the real solution patients have been waiting for. It would upgrade today’s health care insurance from the tattered, complex web that fails to catch millions of sick people each year to proper coverage that allows patients to afford what their physicians prescribe. We need additional reforms to ensure that all people are similarly protected.

Only then will we have truly solved the affordability issue for patients.

Peter Kolchinsky is a founder and managing partner of RA Capital Management and writes on the Biotech Social Contract.

  • I don’t pay anything for the many medications that I must take and I don’t pay anything for my other healthcare. This is because I have Medicaid. I have many medical conditions, so I must see doctors about once a week. I was hospitalized three times in 2019. I am 69 years old and I have been disabled for my entire life.

Comments are closed.